Podcast: Macro Waves
Negative interest rates, a blessing for shoppers, a headache for savers 10/28/2019

How negative rates can impact households and their savings? In this second part, we will see with William De Vijlder that there is no easy answer to this question given the heterogeneity of households and assets.

TRANSCRIPT // Negative interest rates, a blessing for shoppers, a headache for savers : October 2019

Part 2 - Negative interest rates, a blessing for shoppers, a headache for savers

When interest rates are very low to negative, is it good or bad news for households?

The textbook answer is that it’s good news because low rates boost GDP growth and hence household income growth. Behind this simple answer, there is a world of complexity though questions like:

1. Do we look at assets, at liabilities or at both, i.e. assets minus liabilities?

2. Do we look at the household sector in the aggregate or at specific types of households?

Let’s start with the liability side. First of all, what do you mean by it?

By liabilities, I mean three different things:

1. The value of existing credits

When interest rates drop, often credits can be refinanced at a lower rate. Think of mortgages: this makes households better off.

 

2. The ease of access to new credits

Access becomes easier because the interest charge on the loan of a certain size declines. Banks may also ease their standards.

 

3. The present value of future commitments

This is a tricky one. Future commitments are expenditures you will have to make in the future, typically when you have retired. To assess what this represents today, they need to be discounted. The discount rate is the interest rate you get on your assets without taking any risk. And here’s the issue: when interest rates drop, the present value of future commitments increases significantly.

Let’s now turn to the assets side.

With assets I mean several things:

1. The value of existing assets

The price of an asset is the discounted value of future cash-flows. When interest rates decline, all else remaining the same, the asset price increases. Think of the reaction of equity, bond and property prices to a decline in the official interest rates.

 

2. The expected return on these assets

When the central bank cuts interest rates, bank deposit rates decline, so going forward, financial income will be lower. The same applies when investing in bonds. Today, many markets even have negative yields, even for long maturities.

However, most households can avoid being subject to negative interest rates by putting their savings in a bank deposit, which for legal and/or commercial reasons are offering a positive or at least non-negative rate of interest. There are exceptions though: private banking clients of certain banks in certain countries.

 

3. The capacity to let assets grow, that is to save

 

So the difference between assets and liabilities is then simply the net effect.

Indeed, but it’s very hard to determine because influences go in opposite directions. In the end, the key question when assessing the effectiveness of a very expansionary monetary policy is what happens to the savings rate.

Several channels can be distinguished?

1. Faster economic growth will lead to an increase in employment and hence household income. This should boost the volume of household savings.

2. Low rates reduce the opportunity cost of spending money today, rather than tomorrow. This is called the substitution effect. It reduces the savings rate.

3. The income effect has the opposite effect: a decline in interest rates implies lower financial income out of a given size of financial assets. As a consequence, households may decide to save more and spend less.

4. Households may also spend less, save more, take a mortgage to buy a house because rates are low. This implies a substitution between consumption and capital formation.

5. Finally, declining interest rates may boost property prices and equity markets. This can support consumer spending via a wealth effect, and hence weigh on the volume of savings.

Then there is the question of whether we look at the household sector in the aggregate or at specific types of households? Why is the difference important?

1. Households are very different, they’re very heterogeneous.

2. Some considerable debt and limited assets, so they gain from lower interest rates when they refinance a loan.

3. Others have equities and property. They gain as well.

4. Still others have bonds: they are faced with declining coupons. If coupons are halved, you need twice the assets to maintain the same standard of living if you expenditures are paid for by the coupons.

5. People may be unemployed and rate cuts may indirectly give them a new job.

So depending who you consider, the effects of low or even negative rates can be hugely positive (from unemployed to becoming employed) or very negative. Research by the ECB shows that the overall effect is positive.

More Podcasts

On the Same Theme

Mobility: rising trend continues as pandemic eases 6/21/2021
Between 8 and 14 June, the number of new Covid-19 cases worldwide continued to decline, dropping 9% from 2.9 million to 2.64 million. This marked the sixth consecutive week of falls. On the vaccination front, more than 1.6 billion people around the world have now received at least one dose of a Covid-19 vaccine, or 21% of the global population.
Inflation higher for longer? The interplay between productivity, profit margins and pricing power 6/14/2021
A complex interplay between unit labour costs, profit margins and pricing power will determine whether the current increase in inflation will be longer-lasting. Traditionally, in the early phase of a recovery, unit labour costs decline on the back of increased productivity. This should cushion the impact of higher input prices on profit margins. Subsequently, unit labour costs should increase but this does not imply that margins should decline. Given the strength of the growth acceleration, the fact that alternatives for meeting robust demand often do not exist and that going for market share makes no sense when faced with supply constraints, the conditions seem to be met for a rather significant transmission of higher input prices in producer output prices.
International trade: strong dynamism 6/14/2021
Indicators related to international trade remain very strong. Even though the most recent CPB figures are for March, world trade in volumes (both exports and imports) increased 2.2% m/m, pushing the quarterly rise to 3.5% in Q1 2021. This represents a solid growth that was almost identical to that recorded in the previous quarter.
Mobility: nearly back to normal in many countries 6/14/2021
The easing of the pandemic has continued for the fifth consecutive week across the world. The acceleration of vaccination programmes has allowed a gradual reopening of economies. Visits to retail and leisure facilities continued to rise in the main developed economies, marking a return nearly to normal in the week of 28 May to 8 June. 
Uncertainty declining across the board 6/7/2021
Our different uncertainty gauges are complementary, in terms of scope or methodology, yet, based on the latest readings, they all point towards a reduction in uncertainty. Such a uniform, positive message is quite unique.
Mobility remains on a rising trend in the main advanced countries 6/7/2021
Visits to retail and leisure facilities continued to rise in the main advanced countries. The biggest increase in the week came in France. The improving trend has had a visible impact on the service sector, as can be seen in the latest service sector PMI.
Central bank inflation forecasts: ‘Trust us, we know better’ 5/31/2021
Strong belief in the quality of central bank economic forecasts enhances monetary transmission and hence the effectiveness of monetary policy. In the current environment of rising inflationary pressures, the belief of market participants that central banks have better forecasting skills should limit the rise in inflation expectations. Research casts doubt on whether such a belief is warranted. Although Fed staff projections tend to have lower forecast errors than private sector forecasts, the difference has narrowed since the 1990s. In the Eurozone, forecast errors for inflation of the Eurosystem/ECB staff projections were equal to those of the Survey of Professional Forecasters.
Increased mobility and faster vaccine rollouts in Europe 5/31/2021
With the fall in Covid-19 cases and rising vaccination levels, retail and recreation mobility continues to rise. Only Belgium saw a decrease last week, but its level remains the highest in Europe. In the US, mobility is almost back to normal. However, it is continuing to decrease in Japan, with the seven-day moving average down 22% compared with the reference level.
Supply bottlenecks and the inflation outlook 5/25/2021
In countries where restrictions on mobility are lifted, demand picks up suddenly, causing an imbalance with supply, which takes more time to react, in particular when value chains are long and complex. In recent months, companies have been reporting longer delivery lags and rising input costs, but the historical experience in the US and the euro area shows that the impact on inflation should be temporary and limited. Nevertheless, in bond markets, break-even inflation has increased significantly in recent months, reflecting investor worries about the risk of upside surprises to inflation. Should supply-side pressures ease in coming months, one would expect break-even inflation to decline as well. 
Easing of the pandemic and growth in footfall to retail and leisure facilities 5/25/2021
The Covid-19 pandemic continues to slow around the world. As health protection measures are gradually relaxed, footfall to retail and leisure facilities continued to rise in the main developed economies.

ABOUT US Three teams of economists (OECD countries research, emerging economies and country risk, banking economics) make up BNP Paribas Economic Research Department.
This website presents their analyses.
The website contains 2732 articles and 723 videos