Definitions
A zombie firm is generally defined as any firm that is active in the market but with low productivity, high debt and poor profitability. The definition and measurement of the phenomenon are not subject to a widespread consensus. Amongst the existing versions, we would refer in particular to that of the OECD (Adalet McGowan et al, 2017), which defines a zombie firm as one that has existed for more than ten years and whose operating income has not covered debt servicing costs for a period of more than three consecutive years[1]. The Bank of France uses another definition, that proposed by Caballero et al (2008) in their pioneering article on zombie firms in Japan[2]: a zombie firm refers to a company that is fragile but that benefits from particularly favourable financing terms[3],[4]. Banerjee and Hoffmann (2020) consider a zombie firm to be an unprofitable company with a low market valuation for a two-year period[5]. Whatever definition one uses, the identification of zombie firms requires a distinction to be drawn between a temporary fall in a company’s cash reserves (liquidity problem) and its inability to meet future debt repayment deadlines (solvency problem).
The issue of zombification was widely discussed following the Japanese crisis of the 1990s, after the bursting of real estate and financial market bubbles that weakened the country’s economy. Looking beyond the Japanese example, the current shock means that the issue has reared its head again, raising a number of questions. Where are we now, particularly in Europe? What are the causes, real or monetary, of the zombification of economies? Are these economies suffering from lasting macroeconomic effects, most notably in terms of productivity? Will the current crisis and public policies supporting economic activity accelerate the phenomenon of zombification? If so, what would a suitable response be? This article will attempt to provide some aspects of the answers. We will focus our analysis specifically on European countries. We will examine mainly the macroeconomic situation, so will not cover all aspects of the question in detail. To this extent, this article should be seen, above all, as food for thought.
The current situation, causes and consequences of zombification
Where are we now? A brief overview of current conditions
Zombie firms now play a more important role in developed economies than they did in the past. According to Banerjee and Hofmann (2020), who looked only at listed companies (the number of listed zombie firms as a percentage of the total number of listed firms), 15% of firms could be classified as zombies in 2017, from around 4% at the end of the 1980s[6]. Over the past three decades, this proportion has tended to rise following crises and then fall again in subsequent years. However, the zombification phenomenon has become more persistent.
Although there are differences in estimates of their number, the rising trend in the share of zombie firms in advanced economies is widely recognised. This said, as demonstrated by the work of Hallak et al (2018)[7], the picture varies considerably across European countries. For instance, Greece is the European economy with the greatest share of zombie firms, at close to 25%. However, this 2013 estimate should be treated with some caution given the highly difficult Greek macroeconomic situation at the time. The proportion in Spain (at around 20%) is twice that in Italy or France. The share of capital held in zombie firms is also significantly higher in Greece than in France or Germany. This hierarchy has been confirmed by the work of the OECD[8].
How can we explain the rise in zombification?
As discussed in the introduction, the zombification phenomenon has grown in scale since the 2000s, mirroring the earlier pattern in Japan. It should be noted that in the early 1990s Japan suffered a long deflation of real estate and financial market assets, which undermined the value of collateral. Zombification was in part related to difficulties in the banking sector. Numerous analyses of the situation in Japan have highlighted the lack of a rapid restructuring of banks following the bursting of the bubble and the rise in non-performing loans. The authorities’ response was thus too late and too timid. In order to avoid booking losses, Japanese banks continued to lend to unprofitable firms[9]. In reality, for a bank, accurately assessing the capital losses in the event of non-redemption of a loan leads to an increase in provisioning and a deterioration of its financial situation.
Thus, zombification could result from banks’ difficulties, particularly the most vulnerable ones for which making non-profitable loans remains the most viable solution (difficulties which, in some countries, could be amplified by the close links between banks and their client firms through crossed shareholdings). This outcome is consistent with the fact that zombie firms are more likely to have ties with fragile banks, as has been highlighted by a number of studies[10]. Other studies (Acharya et al 2020)[11] have suggested that lending to zombie firms has a deflationary effect by creating excess production capacity. This can complicate the task of monetary authorities and delay an increase in interest rates (see following paragraph). According to some authors, one of the main reasons for the proliferation of zombie firms in Europe, is the rapid and long lasting fall in interest rates since the early 1980s which has reduced financial pressures on all companies. Massive interventions by the European Central Bank (ECB), through cuts in its policy rates and a substantial asset purchasing programme (Quantitative Easing), have fed through into the loans granted to non-financial companies in the eurozone, whose borrowing costs have fallen in a virtually continuous manner (Chart 1). The fall in rates may have thus encouraged increased financial risk-taking by firms that would have behaved differently had rates been higher.
The supply of liquidity from central banks and the relaxation of financing conditions may have indeed contributed to supporting viable firms that only faced temporary cash flow needs, but, in the meantime, may also have supported non-viable firms. Without monetary – or fiscal – interventions, the weakest firms would not withstand negative shocks and would be squeezed out of the market. That said, if such policies persist, they can maintain non-viable firms in the market and limit the ‘ordered’ restructuring of firms, through the bankruptcy process (see below). However, the link between low interest rates and zombie firms seems somewhat too reductionist - particularly in the eurozone – and is not fully established in the literature[12]. Furthermore, as already discussed, the weight of zombie firms varies significantly between the countries in the eurozone, even though member States all share the same monetary policy.
Thus it is difficult to blame low interest rates as the only catalyst for zombification. The best brake on this phenomenon could also be stronger economic growth[13] and a higher level of investment. The issue of the deficit of investment relative to the level of available savings is a pressing topic in the global economy at the moment, particularly in the eurozone. Within the currency union, the imbalance between savings and investment (public and private) has grown since the crisis of 2008-2009. An increase in investment, at constant savings levels, would be beneficial for medium-term economic growth and would reduce the downward pressure on interest rates.
It is worth highlighting a reciprocal causality: on the one hand, the fall in interest rates could amplify the process of zombification, which depresses investment. On the other hand, weak investment levels relative to savings depress both economic activity and interest rates. The two effects – monetary and real – may keep zombie firms in the market and therefore appear difficult to isolate. Lastly, the effects of higher interest rates on the zombification process are uncertain.
Any increase, all other things being equal, would have the significant effect of forcing firms out of the market[14]. Meanwhile, without the substantial monetary support of recent years, current GDP levels and inflation in the eurozone would have been much lower[15].
Other structural factors, specific to each country, partly explain zombification and the differences in its trend between eurozone countries. Several studies stress the importance of the way in which struggling companies are dealt with in different countries. When the restructuring system is efficient, with relatively short and low-cost procedures, the reallocation of bank loans from struggling firms to more productive firms is quicker and the depreciation of assets is more limited. Conversely, when the system is less efficient, the process of “creative destruction” is held back. According to some authors, if “losses” are considered to be significant by banks, it may be in their interest to continue to lend to these vulnerable companies[16]. This perpetuates the zombification cycle. On this point, and based on World Bank estimates[17], we can see major differences between European countries, with France and Italy both having long bankruptcy processes (over 18?months on average). Expanding our sample to include the rest of the world, Europe is well-positioned overall, with 14 countries in the top 20 of the rankings.
To conclude this section, alongside the macroeconomic causes, we will consider some factors from a firm’s perspective. Is there a ‘typical’ zombie firm? How does a firm turn into a zombie? It is not just a question of macroeconomic conditions: are there prior conditions or propensities? In board terms, zombies are companies that are less productive, more heavily indebted and less profitable than others. Banerjee and Hofmann (2020) add the following characteristics to this profile: much smaller companies, which recruit and invest less (in physical and intangible assets), negative cash holding, paying fewer dividends, issuing more shares and benefiting from “subsidised” loans (defined here as loans with interest rates that are not significantly higher than those of non-zombie firms despite zombie firms’ lower profitability and higher risk profile). Although they are more heavily indebted, they also generally seek to reduce their borrowing.
Why is this worrying?
The increase in the number of zombie firms could have contributed to the downward trend in potential growth in OECD countries since the end of the 1990s, through two channels: the slowdown in total factor productivity (TFP) and lower business investment.
Before becoming zombies, companies experience a deterioration in profitability, productivity and investment levels. Once they have become zombies, these firms remain less productive and tend to invest less than other companies[18], which slows down productivity gains in the economy. Thus, according to estimates from the Bank of International Settlements (BIS)[19], when the share of zombie firms in the economy increases by 1%, growth in TFP falls by around 0.3 percentage points (pp). When a large number of non-productive companies remains in the market, the process of “creative destruction” is affected. In theory, better-performing companies should push their weaker competitors out of the market, to enable – through composition effects – an increase in average productivity and a reallocation of workers to more productive firms. Most empirical studies confirm that the survival of insolvent firms is a drag on employment[20], productivity and allocation of capital to viable firms. The less efficient allocation of labour resources also works through the phenomenon of trapping highly-qualified workers in companies with relatively low productivity, as has been observed in many OECD countries. All these factors eventually damage potential growth.
Maintaining non-viable firms in the market also creates congestion effects in the real economy: an increase in competition, which, without stimulating innovation, puts downward pressure on prices and thus affects profitability at unchanged costs. This also raises barriers to entry for new market entrants. Moreover, inefficient allocation of resources can, by extension, reduce productivity gains, as seen in southern Europe[21].
In parallel, some studies suggest a crowding-out effect regarding the banking system[22]: supporting zombie firms makes it harder, both directly and indirectly, for viable firms to access credit. According to these studies, the access to credit for healthy firms is limited first indirectly, by damaging competition from zombie firms whose continued existence in the market drives down prices and thus reduces profits for their viable rivals.
This drop in profits is then viewed negatively by lenders, who are hence less willing to lend for investment projects. On top of this, a direct effect, resulting from bank provisioning, is mentioned by Acharya et al (2019)[23]. This study concludes that less well-capitalised banks can set aside insufficient provisions for losses on non-performing loans. These loans are therefore extended and come to represent a significant share of lending by poorly-capitalised banks; and the balance of lending capacity then becomes insufficient to provide lending to more viable firms. However, the new IFRS9 accounting standards, in force since 2018, seeks to mitigate this effect. The restriction of borrowing options for healthy firms makes it harder to invest, such that once again, zombification holds back potential economic growth.
The economic shock from Covid-19 has hit growth prospects and increased the threat of a spread of zombie firms. Although this is a real concern, this has to be put in perspective.
Covid-19 crisis: a risk of an acceleration in zombification?
What was the financial condition of private European firms before the pandemic struck?
The overall financial position of European non-financial companies (NFCs) had improved since the 2008 crisis, in terms of their level of indebtedness, which has fallen in virtually all European countries (Chart?5). Debt reduction was particularly noticeable in Spain and Portugal, where a significant rebalancing took place after the sharp increase in real estate prices. The improvement has continued until 2019. In 2020, NFC debt started to rise again, steeply, against the background of the crisis – driven notably by the substantial loan guarantee schemes introduced by governments. Part of the increase in European NFCs’ debt in 2020 can be correlated with the matching increase, in certain countries (notably France), in deposits, as some companies have stored up this financing to cover future expenditure. Although the situation varies from country to country, margin levels have stabilised overall since the crisis of 2008 whilst the need (or capacity) for financing has reduced (increased). However, this last point saw a degree of deterioration in 2018 and 2019.
Liquidity (and solvency?) risks have risen during the crisis
The Covid-19 crisis is unprecedented and three-pronged. It is simultaneously a shock to demand, supply and uncertainty. In contrast to 2008-2009, it is not the result of excessive risk-taking by economic agents. The scale of the contraction in economic activity in 2020 was unprecedented and could leave a lasting mark on the productive fabric of European nations. The economic catch-up process will depend on the resilience of companies as we come out of the crisis and the continuation, or otherwise, of fiscal support over the coming quarters. On a macroeconomic level, potential growth has been affected throughout the crisis, due to in particular the drop in the number of hours worked per employee. According to ECB estimates[24], by 2022 the level of eurozone potential output would still be 3% below the forecast carried out before the crisis.
By sector, services have been harder hit by health restrictions than industry, especially in countries where these measures were the most stringent (France and Spain for example)[25]. Transport services, retail and hotels and restaurants displayed a particularly sharp fall in their added value during the first half of 2020 (Chart 6).
Firms in these sectors may therefore face a greater lack of liquidity than others, given the rapid drop in their revenues and the limited capacity to adjust their costs in the short term (even though short-time working schemes helped mitigate these costs to some extent). If these same companies faced financial difficulties before the crisis, these liquidity issues could, in the end, increase the risk of defaults.
According to estimates from the European Commission in May 2020[26], between 58% and 75% of the total lack of liquidity in Europe was focused on financially-vulnerable companies (in terms of debt to equity or EBIT to revenue ratios). Among the eurozone’s four biggest economies, the ECB’s research[27] shows that Spain has the biggest share of firms facing either liquidity problems or with negative working capital and high levels of borrowing. These estimates were confirmed by Bank of Spain research[28], which indicated that nearly 70% of private firms in the country were likely to have additional liquidity needs between April and December 2020, with sharp increases in financial difficulties in tourism and leisure, the automotive sector and transport services. However, Spain is by no means alone, with a large number of companies experiencing liquidity issues in France and Germany too.
Measures introduced by national governments, such as the massive use of short-time working and government-guaranteed lending by banks, seem, however, to have significantly reduced liquidity risks for European companies. The same Bank of Spain report considers that three-quarters of liquidity needs could be covered by these guaranteed loans.
Firms are also facing difficulties in the labour market. According to the OECD, the share of the most-at-risk jobs is particularly high in Spain (Chart 7), and remains more moderate in Germany and France. The structure of employment and the proportion of public-sector jobs affect these figures.
***
Conclusion: Is the Covid-19 shock an accelerator for zombification? Let’s not rush to judgement
Despite the current difficulties and the likelihood that the health shock will have lasting consequences for the economy, fears of zombification should be tempered somewhat. First, it is difficult at this stage to have a clear view. The exceptional lockdown measures introduced by governments make it difficult at this stage to distinguish between companies suffering only from liquidity problems and those that are insolvent. More precisely, until the economic situation has been fully normalised it will probably be too soon to draw such a distinction and sort the firms worthy of support from the rest.
The Covid-19 crisis raises twin fears: a wave of business failures on the one hand, or an insufficient number on the other. The smaller the wave, the greater the risk of zombification. However, we do not believe that one should worry (or at least not yet) about this political dilemma, which opposes on the one hand massive indiscriminate support that runs the risk of fuelling zombification, and on the other more limited support, allowing creative destruction but at the cost of higher unemployment and the loss of some viable businesses. Faced with the risk of zombification and the benefit of protecting productive and human capital, the latter wins out. The risk of feeding zombification is a lesser evil than that of destroying ‘good’ capital, especially as the former can be managed further down the line whilst the latter has bigger immediate and long-term consequences, which will be harder to reverse. In other words, the more the policy mix softens the economic shock, the more the consequences of the shock, which carry the risk of increased zombification, will be contained.
Without massive fiscal support, the collapse of European economies would have been much worse than it has been. Financially healthy and productive companies could have been forced to the wall by temporary cash flow problems. The social consequences of the crisis, through a steeper increase in unemployment, would have been even longer lasting (particularly if one acknowledges Europe’s imperfect labour mobility between sectors and countries). Concomitantly, the very flexible and accommodating monetary policy from the ECB – and other major central banks – has allowed a widespread decrease in interest rates across a broad spectrum of maturities for all economic agents. In particular, this has facilitated fiscal support. Without it, sovereign spreads (the differences in yields on different countries’ government debt) would have widened, the risk of financial fragmentation would have resurfaced and companies in the more vulnerable nations would have suffered for a long time to come.
Then, once the shock had eased and public support been scaled back, the European economy would have remained in a weakened state with corporate debt remaining high. Long-term unemployment could then have taken hold and business bankruptcies seen significant increases. Although business failures have so far been limited by public measures to support cash flow and temporary amendments to the legal framework for bankruptcy procedures – notably through waiving of the requirement for directors to declare a cessation of payments – this is only delaying the inevitable for a number of companies[29]. As we come out of the crisis, attention will turn to borrowing levels at European companies. Already, on can expect a sharp rise in business bankruptcies in Europe in 2021[30]: Germany (+12% compared to the 2019 level), France (+25%), Italy (+27%) and Spain (+41%). As indicated in Section 2.b above, the increases in company bankruptcies and indebtedness will have fewer macroeconomic consequences in case of efficient debt restructuring or liquidation framework in place[31]. In this area, Europe is relatively well positioned.
If the risk of increased zombification cannot be rule out following the Covid-19 crisis, what can be done to address it? In the near future, one direct remedy is to strengthen firms’ balance sheets. This must happen through a strengthening of capital via, for example, participating loans – as included in the France Relance programme – or the transformation of government-guaranteed loans into subsidies, a possibility also raised in France. It might also take the form of a restructuring of the debts of companies considered as viable. More broadly, in terms of macroeconomic policy, improvements to recovery and liquidation processes[32] also form part of the measures to be taken. In the longer term, policies on competition, innovation, training and professional mobility are also powerful ways to tackle zombification, to the extent that they improve the creative destruction process and an efficient (re)allocation of resources. The outcome is that it is easier for firms to enter and leave the market. Taken together, such policies would boost potential growth in Europe, which represents the best way of holding back zombification.