Last July, the US Federal Reserve (Fed) expanded its scope of intervention in the money markets. It now has a permanent repo facility (Standing Repo Facility or SRF) in addition to its reverse repo facility (Reverse Repo Program or RRP). These tools should allow the Fed to modulate its supply of central bank money, downwards as well as upwards, in periods of pressure on short-term market rates. In the current context of abundant central bank liquidity and limited supply of government securities, money market funds have made considerable use of the RRP. The ability of the SRF to reduce tension in the event of a drying up of central bank liquidity could, however, be countered by various factors such as the leverage constraints to which primary dealers and banks are subject.
Two tools, a corridor for short-term market rates
In July, the Fed supplemented its monetary policy toolkit by creating a permanent repo facility (Standing Repo Facility or SRF) to complement its reverse repo facility (Reverse Repo Program or RRP)[1]. In contrast to firm purchases or sales of securities, these allow the temporary sterilisation (RRP) or injection (SRF) of central bank liquidity. The two facilities aim to create a corridor for short-term market rates, and more specifically for the (private[2]) repo lending markets. The aim is to be able to attenuate situations of excess or insufficient liquidity and thus ensure good transmission of monetary policy. These (private) markets concentrate very large trading volumes (more than USD4,000 billion in outstandings in 2021 according to SIFMA) and are one of the main sources for day-to-day refinancing and cash management for US financial institutions. In addition, the effective Fed Funds rate, which determines a large swathe of interest rates for loans to consumers and companies, is highly sensitive to changes in the cost of repos[3]. Lastly, the median repo rate (Secured Overnight Financing Rate, SOFR[4]) will serve as the main benchmark rate for new derivatives contracts in the US from 1 January 2022.
RRP: draining off reserves and providing a floor for short rates
Under the RRP the Fed places Treasury securities it holds on its balance sheet on repo with counterparties (banks, primary dealers, Government Sponsored Enterprises and money market funds).
By using this facility, banks and non-banking institutions make a secured loan (cash against Treasuries) to the Fed. Another way of interpreting this transaction is to consider that a financial institution makes a ‘deposit’ with the Fed in exchange for the transfer of ownership, for a predetermined period, of the securities provided as collateral.
This type of transaction transits through bank balance sheets such that it reduces the reserves that banks hold with the Fed. The Fed records the reverse repo in its liabilities as a debt and debits the current account of the intermediary bank (central bank reserves) for the same amount. When a bank enters into a repo transaction with the Fed, the transaction results simply in an exchange of assets on its balance sheet (reverse repo against reserves) with no effect on its overall size. Where a bank is acting on behalf of a money market fund, it debits the deposit account of its client, and its balance sheet is reduced (reduction both in reserves on the asset side and in deposits on the liability side). This type of transaction does not change the size of the Fed’s balance sheet, but does change the make-up of its liabilities (repo against reserves)[5].
The RRP seeks to create a floor for short-term market rates. Central banks’ asset purchasing programmes (QE), the main aim of which is to reduce bond yields, create abundant central bank liquidity (central bank reserves) and bank deposits[6]. Under such conditions, the programme has the effect of reducing downward pressure on short-term rates by encouraging money market funds and GSEs to “lend“ part of their cash to the Fed rather than on markets (repo, Fed Funds) where demand has dried up. By temporarily sterilising the excess reserves created and by reducing banks’ balance sheets, it also reduces the balance sheet constraints that banks are subject to.
SRF: injecting reserves and providing a ceiling for short-term rates
Under the SRF, some counterparties (primary dealers and depository institutions) place Treasury debt securities, debt securities and MBS issued by the mortgage guarantee and refinancing agencies (GSE and public agencies) on repo with the Fed. The Fed records the repo in assets as a credit and credits the current account of the intermediary bank (central bank reserves) for the same amount in its liabilities. When a bank enters into a repo transaction with the Fed on its own behalf, the transaction results in a debt to the Fed (the repo) being recorded as a liability on its balance sheet and an increase of reserves held at the central bank on its asset side. Where a bank is acting on behalf of a primary dealer, it credits the deposit account of its client. All other things being equal, the facility increases banks’ reserves with the central bank and enlarges their balance sheets. As with firm purchases of securities (QE), the SRF increases the size of the Fed’s balance sheet[7]. A fundamental difference between the two is, obviously, the difference in maturity of the respective transactions.
The SRF seeks to create a ceiling for short-term market rates. In a situation of insufficient central bank liquidity, it will reduce pressure by offering credit institutions the opportunity to rebuild their stock of reserves and thus be able to meet the cash needs expressed on the money markets. The SRF system allows the temporary ‘monetisation’ of securities and a reduction of the liquidity constraints faced by banks (for regulatory or internal liquidity risk management reasons).
RRP and SRF transactions are made on a daily basis, each working day, and within the cumulative daily limits applicable individually to each counterparty. Under the RRP programme, each eligible counterparty can, on its own initiative, ‘lend’ the Fed up to USD160 billion in cash on a daily basis. These ‘deposits’ earn 0.05% (Chart 1). Under the SRF programme, each eligible counterparty can ‘borrow’ up to USD120 billion from the Fed on a daily basis. Transactions are charged at the marginal lending rate (0.25%) and capped in the aggregate at USD500 billion[8].
The RRP facility has been widely used by money market funds
The Fed carries out the majority of its reverse repo transactions (via banks) with money market funds (MMF), the only institutions with an incentive to take part[9].
First introduced in the autumn of 2013, one year before the ending of QE3 (the Fed’s third quantitative easing programme) and two years before the beginning of the post-crisis monetary tightening, this facility saw high levels of participation by money market funds (with interest rates of between 0.01% and 0.07% up to the end of 2015) and helped establish a floor for short-term interest rates[10].
Reactivated in March 2021 (with a first increase in the individual cap from USD30 billion to USD80 billion on 17 March, an expansion of the list of eligible counterparties on 30 April, the introduction of a positive interest rate on 16 June and a second increase in the individual cap to USD160 billion on 22 September), the RRP facility is once again, and to an even greater degree, widely used (Chart 2).
Since the beginning of the year, the system nearly fully offsets the effect on central bank reserves of a drying up of the Treasury’s account with the Fed (see box). On average, since early June, USD1,000 billion of cash has been ‘taken back’ each day by the Fed under RRP. At 30 September, MMF cash ‘deposits’ with the Fed peaked at USD1,600 billion; the average daily outstanding amount reached USD1,400 billion in October and the first fortnight of November. 84% of cash is placed by government funds[11], 16% by prime funds[12]. Independent money market funds are slightly more active than those affiliated to a banking group: the former make 59% of guaranteed ‘loans’ to the Fed, the latter, 41%.
A deep reallocation of the MMFs’ portfolios
Data on money market portfolio structures published by the Investment Company Institute (ICI) and the Office of Financial Research (OFR) show that the increase in MMF ‘deposits’ with the Fed resulted only temporarily from an increase in subscriptions to fund shares. The increasing scale of the RRP system has in reality been caused by a reallocation of the money market funds’ portfolios (Chart 3).
At the beginning of the year, banks sought to reorient non-operational deposits (deposits from institutional clients) to MMF shares in order to slim down balance sheets (without affecting liquidity ratios[13]). Subscriptions to MMF shares increased as a result.
In the absence of remunerative investment opportunities, MMFs eligible for the RRP facility have temporarily held the cash received in the form of deposits with the Fed. In March 2021, the increase in MMF ‘loans’ to the Fed thus resulted from an expansion of MMF portfolios (Chart 4). The phenomenon was, however, short-lived considering that, as of April, MMF assets did not change that much.
Subsequently, MMFs uptake of the RRP facility was more the result of a substitution effect. First, the drying up of the market for T-bills[14] prevented funds from reinvesting as securities on their balance sheets matured.
Secondly, the marked increase in deposits on bank balance sheets (linked to QE, the provision of guaranteed loans to companies and ‘stimulus checks’ financed by the reduction of the Treasury’s account with the Fed) reduced banks’ need to refinance themselves with the Federal Home Loan Banks (FHLB) in the form of secured loans (advances[15]).
At the end of June, the volume of secured loans from the FHLB to banks reached a low point for the last twenty years (USD360 billion, from USD800 billion in March 2020), as did their issuance of debt securities. As with T-bills, this reduction in the supply of high-quality short-term paper prevented the funds, and particularly government funds from renewing their agency debt portfolios. Since April, the contraction in the stock of Treasury and agency debt on MMF balance sheets has been counterbalanced by an increase in MMF ‘deposits’ with the Fed (Chart 4). From June, the interest paid by the Fed has also increased the facility’s attractions.
Residual capacity for RRP uptake remains substantial
We have used data from the Office of Financial Research to assess the residual amount of cash that eligible money market funds could place with the Fed under RRP (on the basis of portfolio structures on 30 September). There are 98 money market funds on the list of eligible counterparties for the RRP. Of these, 80 funds had active reverse repo transactions with the Fed at 30 September, for a total value of USD1,439 billion[16]. On this date, the MMFs allocated an average of 30% of their resources to the scheme (Chart 5). Theoretically, each MMF can ‘lend’ up to USD160 billion a day to the Fed. In practice, the sums involved for the eligible funds are well below this cap[17].
The total value of their public debt security portfolios does, however, give an indication of residual potential. Since the re-activation of the RRP facility, the 80 participating MMFs have reduced their portfolios of Treasuries and Agencies by USD926 billion (64% of the USD1,439 billion placed with the Fed under RRP on 30 September). In the extreme case where none of the stock of Treasuries and Agencies held on the balance sheets of these MMFs were renewed, their residual capacity to make reverse repo loans to the Fed would be nearly USD1,400 billion (Chart 6).
The SRF, an advance indicator of tension on liquidity
Through the SRF facility, the Fed has given itself a new tool to detect and address possible shortages in central bank cash. Introduced as an emergency temporary measure in September 2019, this facility allowed the repo market crisis to be absorbed[18]. However, it failed in the run-up to this shock when regulatory constraints on liquidity, exacerbated by the reduction in the Fed’s balance sheet, prevented banks from meeting the demand for cash expressed by the money markets[19]. Of little use in the current conditions of abundant liquidity, the possibility of converting securities into reserves at any time, without the stigma associated with the use of the discount window, could however lead to certain banks inflating their portfolios of Treasuries and Agencies. This could be the case for mid-sized banks which, unlike their bigger rivals, hold stocks of securities that are well below the individual SRF cap. The system’s ability to attenuate monetary tensions in the event of insufficient central bank money could however be compromised by various factors.
Balance sheet constraints
A first factor is the absence of netting off of repo transactions with the Fed. Under a repo transaction (collateralised loan), the borrower’s balance sheet increases: liabilities increase by the amount borrowed (in the form of the repo), assets by the cash received. The security used as collateral remains on the balance sheet of the borrower (which retains its ‘economic ownership’).
The Fed’s repo transactions are carried out on the tripartite repo platform operated by Bank of New York Mellon, which plays the role of clearing bank. However, use of the tripartite market does not allow the netting off of positions, unlike transactions carried out via the Fixed Income Clearing Corporation (FICC).
As we approach the closing of accounts, the liquidity offered by the Fed through the SRF, thus risks being inaccessible to the primary dealers or depository institutions most constrained by their leverage requirements. Even in 2019, the Fed’s interventions, on their own, were not able to attenuate the tension that had arisen, particularly at the end of the year. Over and above the USD256 billion of liquidity ‘borrowed’ from the Fed under its repo transactions on 31 December 2019, dealers partly refinanced their inventory of securities through repo with MMFs that were cleared and settled via the FICC (USD276 billion, Chart 7).
Increased risk of competition
A second factor is the timing of the repo transactions. The Fed plans to carry them out under SRF between 1:30pm and 1:45pm, which is relatively late in the day given the timeslots traditionally used on the repo markets, where the bulk of transactions are concluded very early in the morning[20]. In the event of stress, this could lead borrowers to use the open markets at the beginning of the morning, going beyond their immediate needs for fear that the SRF ceiling will be reached rapidly in the early afternoon and their refinancing needs left unmet. Under such conditions of increased competition, which would push up the cost of repo loans, the Fed could be forced to raise the ceiling for its system.
Reputational risk
Reputational risk is a third factor, which might weigh on the willingness of banks to use SRF. Although the names of counterparties to transactions will not be published, there is a non-zero risk that supervisors will see use of the SRF facility as an early signal of bad management of liquidity or individual difficulties in accessing liquidity (as with withdrawals from the discount window). To decrease this reputational risk, the use of the SRF will need to be viewed as a refinancing tool rather than a rescue system. The supervisor is still considering whether banks will be allowed to assume use of the SRF in liquidity stress tests and resolution plans (which is not the case for the discount window).