Eco Week
Editorial

Inflation and the sustainability of public sector debt

05/15/2022
PDF

At first glance, higher inflation seems like good news for governments. After all, inflation erodes the real value of debt and lowers the public debt/GDP ratio through a higher nominal GDP. However, the impact of inflation on public finances depends on whether higher inflation was anticipated by financial markets and on its expected persistence. Both factors would influence the borrowing cost and hence the dynamics of the debt ratio through the difference between this cost and nominal GDP growth. Public finances should benefit from having a central bank that is credible in its ability to keep inflation expectations well anchored and is not afraid of tightening policy when inflation has moved well above target. In the euro area, higher Bund yields cause higher sovereign spreads, reflecting a higher risk premium, which in the longer run will worsen the dynamics of the debt ratio. It implies that fiscal policy also has a role to play by keeping the debt ratio under control.

EUROZONE : SOVEREIGN SPREADS VERSUS BUND

At first glance, higher inflation seems like good news for governments. After all, inflation erodes the real value of debt. Considering that taxes are levied on nominal amounts -income, value added, profits, etc.- tax revenues increase when inflation rises so the burden of servicing the existing debt as a proportion of public revenues declines . Moreover, rising inflation -under the assumption that it is not weighing on real activity and spending- causes an increase in nominal GDP and hence a decline of the public debt/GDP ratio. In this respect, table 1 shows for various euro area countries the public debt ratio level and the inflation forecast for this year1. If the debt/GDP ratio was stable before the increase in inflation, its decline due to a jump in prices could be considered as an increase in fiscal policy leeway.

EUROZONE : REGRESSION RESIDUAL OF SOVEREIGN SPREADS VS. BUND

However, the impact of inflation on public finances also depends on whether higher inflation was anticipated by financial markets and on its expected persistence. An anticipated rise in inflation would have caused an increase in nominal interest rates even before inflation and nominal growth started to pick up, thereby worsening the dynamics of the debt ratio. As a reminder, these dynamics depend on the primary balance -the budget balance excluding interest charges- and the difference between the average cost of debt (r) and nominal GDP growth (g). This implies that an unanticipated inflation shock will have a bigger impact on the path of the debt ratio. It can be argued that the extent of the jump in inflation since the second half of 2021 has to a large degree been unexpected. The persistence of inflation also plays an important role. If it is expected to remain elevated, it will cause an increase in market-based inflation expectations and hence the level of nominal bond yields. Clearly, given the long average maturity of public debt in most countries (table 1), it would take several years until these developments would be fully reflected in a higher average cost of public debt. However, there is a risk that financial markets would increasingly focus on the marginal difference between r and g -whereby ‘marginal’ refers to the cost of newly issued debt- rather than the difference between the average cost of outstanding debt and nominal GDP growth.

A key factor in the perceived persistence of inflation is the attitude of the central bank. Should the credibility of monetary policy be declining, markets would price in an inflation risk premium as a hedge against the possibility of future above-target inflation. This worsens the dynamics of the debt ratio because the market-based expected inflation -which influences the borrowing cost r- could be higher than observed inflation2, which influences nominal growth g. This implies that public finances should benefit from having a central bank that is credible and is not afraid of tightening policy when inflation has moved well above target, even though this may temporarily worsen r – g by lowering real growth in the short run.

Fiscal policy also has a key role to play, however, by keeping the debt ratio under control. In the euro area, the prospect of an increase in the ECB’s policy rates, in combination with rising break-even inflation, has caused a significant increase in German bond yields and a widening in sovereign spreads versus Bunds (chart 1). The latter is a normal phenomenon and reflects the idea that yield-targeting investors need less exposure to higher-yielding euro area sovereigns when German yields have seen a significant increase3. It could also reflect mounting concern about debt sustainability. To explore this further, a regression has been run between the level of the spread and the 10-year Bund yield. Large positive regression residuals would reflect an abnormally high spread given where Bund yields are currently trading. As shown in chart 2, for Italy, the regression residuals have been close to zero as of late, which suggests that the spread widening has been consistent with the rise in German yields. For Spain and in particular Portugal, the regression residuals are increasingly negative, so the increase in Spanish and Portuguese yields has been more limited than expected, considering the rise in German yields.

In order to keep the dynamics of the public debt/GDP ratio under control, both monetary and fiscal policy have a role to play, the former by making sure that inflation expectations remain well anchored, the latter by focusing on the budget deficit.

GROWTH, INFLATION AND PUBLIC FINANCES
THE ECONOMISTS WHO PARTICIPATED IN THIS ARTICLE

Other articles from the same publication

Economic Pulse
Industrial production declining, trade surplus historically low

Industrial production declining, trade surplus historically low

Although Germany returned to positive economic growth in the first quarter of 2022 – with GDP up 0 [...]

Read the article
Economic Pulse
Further contraction in consumer spending likely in the second quarter

Further contraction in consumer spending likely in the second quarter

Inflation is continuing to spread among the various components of the consumer price index (CPI). The energy component fell slightly in April (-2 [...]

Read the article
Economic Pulse
Overall inflation slows but increase of food prices accelerates

Overall inflation slows but increase of food prices accelerates

Latest inflation figures give the Spanish government a little respite. Having approached 10% in March (9.8%), consumer price inflation fell to 8.4% in April [...]

Read the article
Economic Pulse
Weak growth and recession risk

Weak growth and recession risk

The UK economy grew 0.8% q/q in Q1 2022, taking GDP 0.7% above its pre-Covid level of Q4 2019 but falling short of the 1% expansion expected [...]

Read the article
Economic Pulse
Back to pre-pandemic levels in (almost) all developed economies

Back to pre-pandemic levels in (almost) all developed economies

The downward trend in the weekly number of new cases of Covid-19 continued in most regions of the world [...]

Read the article