Another obvious difference is the current level of growth, inflation and the policy rate. All three are higher in the US. These differences have led to an important divergence in the conduct of and communication about monetary policy.
As shown on the next page, theoretically different types of policy can be considered: interest rate decisions which are agnostic with respect to economic data in the short run, data-dependent decisions, state-dependent or calendar-based forward guidance[ii]. The choice will to a large degree depend on the available leeway (is there a lot of room to cut if need be?) and the distance to the target (in case of inflation targeting, what is the gap between observed inflation and the objective of the central bank?).
Consider an economy which is entering a recession with rather high interest rates and inflation dropping below target. In that case, interest rates will be cut swiftly and the central bank will be agnostic to the dataflow, at least until it sees that the policy easing is starting to have its intended effect on growth and inflation.
As growth picks up, markets will start to anticipate a phase of policy normalisation. This may cause a premature tightening of financial conditions (rising bond yields). Calendar-based forward guidance will be used to get a grip on the yield curve. When the target variable is close to the aim, the monetary authority will probably be very data-focused, irrespective of whether policy leeway is considerable or limited: a sequence of strong or weak data can push the target variable beyond the objective or pull it away from it. This is the situation the Federal Reserve is currently in: growth is still satisfactory, although there are downside risks, and inflation is muted, although it is not too low. The ECB on the other hand is confronted with limited leeway (the deposit rate is already very negative and there are market concerns about limits on how much it can buy in the context of QE), whilst inflation is well below target and is very likely to stay there, at least in the short run. State-dependent forward guidance then almost becomes a strategy of last resort. It pushes the timing of the first rate hike far out into the future and it creates an expectation that asset purchases will be conducted for a considerable period of time, considering that the ECB has stated that they will end shortly before it starts raising rates. In doing so, this creates visibility about financing conditions far into the future, which should support credit demand and spending.
Using this framework, it is clear that the Federal Reserve and the ECB are in very different positions and hence adopt very different approaches. The Fed has declared it is data-dependent, so there is basically no guidance (except for the projections of the FOMC members). The ECB on the other hand is data-independent: the policy is entirely built around forward guidance with the gap between observed and target inflation being the key factor. This policy should reduce the sensitivity of eurozone financial markets to data surprises because data will not influence the policy stance as long as inflation is too low versus the central bank’s aim. In the US on the other hand, data-dependent policy should increase the sensitivity of market prices to news, leading to higher volatility. It is to be expected that this in turn will have international spillover effects, via currency, bond and equity markets.